“The Role of Smallpox Vaccination in Mortality Decline in the Great Britain through Eradicating the Disease between XVIII-XX centuries – Facts or a Political Arithmetick?”
“The Role of Smallpox Vaccination in Mortality Decline in the Great Britain through Eradicating the Disease between XVIII-XX centuries – Facts or a Political Arithmetick?”
University of Illinois at Chicago
Department of Economics
“The Role of Smallpox Vaccination in
Mortality Decline
in the Great Britain through
Eradicating the Disease between
XVIII-XX centuries – Facts or a
Political Arithmetick?”
by Mamurjon Rahimov
WHO.ORG
Title:
“The Role of Smallpox Vaccination in Mortality Decline in the Great Britain
through Eradicating the Disease between XVIII-XX centuries – Facts or a
Political Arithmetick?”
“Whoever would understand the political phenomenon
known as ‘The Anti-Vaccination Agitation”- and its magnitude would seem to
indicate it as being at least worth understanding – must remember some one or
two facts, facts obvious enough indeed, but constantly forgotten. And chief
amongst them this, that every opponent of the practice, every skeptic, without
exception, as to its benefits, has in the first instance approached the
question in a spirit at least of impartiality, and probably all his prejudices
strongly in its favor”
-Alfred Milnes
Introduction
In October of 1979, The World Health Organization (WHO),
officially declared smallpox, also known as variola, eradicated. The disease
that was known to mankind as early as 1122 BC in China, took millions of lives
throughout the world (Britannica.com). We all know that WHO is a branch of the
United Nations Organization, and is dedicated to protect the health of the
mankind. However, UN also has many other branches dealing with issues like
business, economy, culture, education, migration, to name a few, and
furthermore, the eradication of smallpox is believed to be a collaborative
achievement of most of these branches, both on local and on global level. If
so, this eradication must have been announced jointly with, if not all, then at
least few other UN branches such as World Bank, UNDP, and UNICEF. It would be
very unfair for medical men to appropriate this great achievement of mankind
all to themselves. Although medical men do not like to mention it too much,
they all recognize that eradication of smallpox was not only their merit.
Economic history has contributed significantly to the
formulation of various economic theories. Among the economists who have found
history to be an important source for their ideas one can cite Adam Smith,
Thomas Malthus, Alfred Marshall, John Maynard Keynes, Milton Friedman, Robert
Solow, and Gary Becker. For economists it is very important to study
population history in order to come up with policies that decrease mortality
and morbidity of the population. Factors like life expectancy, infant mortality
are considered to be key indicators of progress in any country. Longer life
expectancy means more manpower to move the industry, larger consumer base for
products and services.
My purpose here is to elaborate in theoretical and
statistical plausibility of smallpox vaccination eradicating the disease based
on papers written about the smallpox disease, and to seek whether the
vaccination, if efficient at all, weighed substantially in the light of other
forces that caused decline in mortality. It is quite striking to read from Memoirs
of Jacques Casanova, a contemporary, that “More people perish at the hands
of doctors than are cured by them” in those centuries, and in contrast the
common belief that in those centuries medical men suddenly came up with “one-size-fits-all”
cure for one of the most dreadful diseases of all time, which, with little
modifications, if any, continued to be administered worldwide up until the
second half of the XX century.
For several centuries until now, proponents of vaccination
hailed smallpox vaccination to be a proven wonder weapon in the hands of
mankind in eradicating the disease in the world, although there have been a
number of schools of thought that, if not disprove, then diminish the role of
smallpox vaccination in fighting the disease to an insignificant level, which
is the change in the virulence of smallpox.
We must remember from European history that the period in
which the most drastic decline in British smallpox mortality took place
coincides with the time Britain experienced industrial revolution, and thus
improved standards of living must have played crucial role in reducing
susceptibility of the population towards infectious diseases (Krause, 1958). A
good example is a paper written by several researchers from the University of
Liverpool and Manchester that used time-series analysis to study the dynamics
of smallpox in Britain in 1550-1800, and found a striking correlation between
wheat price fluctuations and epidemics (Duncan, 1993; also see Helleiner, 1957).
Economists almost always try to use models in order to
come up with logical interpretations of current and past events. One such
paper (Mokyr, 1993) that tries to explain decline in mortality in the light of
economic forces, used standard theory of utility maximization as a starting
point: Uj = Uj (Xij…Xnj, Lj) where L is composite family life expectancy
variable, subject to the usual budget constraint ∑XiPi = Y. It further
goes on and tries to estimate the rise in knowledge (in hygiene and sanitation,
in particular), relative prices, public goods (convergence towards best
practices), and the like and their consequent influence on decreased
mortality. Economists agree that knowledge always has indirectly influenced
every single area of man’s life, however the paper attempts to go beyond
indirect relationship towards autonomous causality, and since lion’s share of
mortality and morbidity is attributed to smallpox at that period in history, it
does seem that a general rise in the level and scope of knowledge had direct
effect on mortality decline throughout Britain.
Much has been said and written about the practice of
vaccination in general and smallpox vaccination in particular. If you read a
couple articles and books on how lucky we were to obtain the knowledge about
vaccination, you may feel that, if not vaccines, mankind would be wiped out
from the Earth by the dreadful infectious diseases of all kind. While I am
writing this paper, hundreds more new vaccines are being developed in
state-of-the-art medical laboratories and millions of people, young and old,
are being vaccinated, despite the growing opposition from parents, scholars,
and doctors against mandatory mass vaccination. It is interesting to note that
vaccination remains to be the only medical practice that has to be enforced by
law (NVIC.ORG).
A Remarkable Decline in Mortality
Mortality and morbidity of a population, although closely
related, are two different things. I do not want to elaborate that in a number
of developed countries, including the United States, morbidity of the
population has been growing, while mortality has been rather low (NVIC.ORG
statistics). In this paper, I tried to focus on falling of mortality rates in
Britain between 18th and 20th centuries, and the causes
of this remarkable decline. Economic gains from falling mortality can never be
precisely estimated, because human life is such the most precious thing one can
ever have. Between 1750 and 1914 mortality rates went down substantially
everywhere in Europe, of course not at the same pace and the same extent. For
instance, life expectancy in Britain went from 30’s in 1750 to 50’s in 1914,
and crude death rate fell from about 25 per thousand in 1750 to 14-15 per
thousand in 1914. The immediate cause of this dramatic shift is undisputedly
decline in infectious diseases in Europe, but deeper causes of this phenomenon
have been fueling debates among three major overlapping “schools” that have
emerged to explain the causes behind the mortality decline. “Nutritionist”
school stresses improvement in living standards and food consumption as a
result of economic growth to be major causes, whereas “preventist” school
contends that this decline in mortality can be attributed primarily to public
policy such as smallpox vaccination campaigns on mass level and cleaning of
sewage systems. The third school, “exogenists”, claims that the decline in
mortality can be explained by reduced virulence of major infectious diseases on
microbial level and positive changes in climate (Mokyr, 1993).
First inoculation and later vaccination is cited to be
plausible explanation for this decline. Inoculation, in primitive and crude
way, was practiced mainly in a few Oriental and African countries. Due to the
limited scale of inoculation, its efficacy was not known well. People of
England learnt about it in 1721 when Lady Mary Wortley Montagu’s daughter was
inoculated in London (Tucker, 1963).
Inoculation must be formally defined to avoid mixing it
with the more recent practice of vaccination. Smallpox inoculation is the
injection of smallpox virus taken from actual smallpox wound of a patient,
whereas smallpox vaccination is the injection of cowpox virus. The symptoms
these two practices produce slightly differ, but they are both carried out for
the same purpose – developing immunity in people against the actual smallpox
disease. Edward Jenner was the founder of smallpox vaccination in Britain, and
interestingly, it was by his medical induction that he believed that exposing a
person to cowpox would render the person immune to smallpox (1798). Nobody
could prove empirically that this exactly was the case, and for instance
William Hewson was not able to verify through numerous experiments what Jenner
supposedly achieved. Charles Creighton, a learned anti-vaccinator, in his book
Jenner and Vaccination (1889), proved that Jenner not only failed to
demonstrate, experimentally or otherwise, that cowpox and smallpox were
biologically related, but nobody else, until the date Creighton’s own book was
published, had done so (Greenwood, 1930). Besides, the population, which was
subject to various vaccination laws and acts, stubbornly resisted to
vaccination (Milnes, 1897). The City of Leicester became a center of such
resistance, and despite the gloomy prophecies of medical men about huge toll to
be paid due to a large unvaccinated population, it was one of the cities that
suffered least from several epidemics of 19th century (NAVL, 1910).
Legal Side of the Story
In 1840 British Parliament passed “An Act to Extend the
Practice of Vaccination”, by which smallpox inoculation that was used prior to
smallpox vaccination to prevent this disease was made a penal offence. Since
the practice of smallpox inoculation dates back to 1721, it turns out this
life-destroying practice lasted for a hundred and twenty years!
The first compulsory vaccination law was Lord Lyttelton’s
Act in 1853. Lord Lyttelton is quoted to have said, “It is unnecessary for me
to speak of the certainty of vaccination as a preventive of small-pox, that
being a point on which the whole medical profession have arrived at complete
unanimity”. Despite a growing number of post-vaccinal morbidity and mortality
cases (Krause, 1958), Britain passed another landmark vaccine law in 1867 - the
vaccination law of England, which at once was put in force (Milnes, 1897).
Stakes Behind the Vaccination
Often, if not always,
there are huge financial interests behind political goals. Due to mostly
qualitative information concerning the vaccination in the stated period, and
inexistence of reliable statistical body for the most part of it, “There is no
means of accurately gauging the amount paid for treating diseases subsidiary,
or arising from vaccination” (NAVL, 1910). However, the below brief table for
Ireland will illustrate that substantial finances were committed to the
vaccination practice.
Table 1. Annual Reports for the
Local Government Board for Ireland:
Year Ending 31 March
|
Fees paid to Medical Officers
|
Other Expenses in carrying out Vaccination Acts
|
1905
|
£ 16, 196 183
|
£ 1, 893 9 4
|
1906
|
10, 168 178
|
1, 857 143
|
1907
|
8, 430 4 6
|
1, 973 17 5
|
1908
|
8, 061 140
|
1, 938 181
|
1909
|
8, 006 0 0
|
1, 963 0 0
|
Fascination vs. Repulsion with
Numbers
Among all the economists of the history, I admire Adam
Smith most of all. Adam Smith’s works have been inspiring many economists
throughout centuries, and many scholars can’t help mentioning him in the course
of their work. His pen did leave few stones unturned, and each time with an
economic point of view. Although most of the modern terms were inexistent at
his time, he described things his own way and often cut to the core of the
matter. I had to refer to his famous book, Wealth of Nations, for many times
in the past, and the most recent review of it gave me a term that has become an
anchor for my paper. That term is “Political Arithmetick”. Adam Smith
remarkably acknowledged ‘I have no great faith in political arithmetick’
(Smith, Wealth of Nations, I, p.534). In a 1785 letter written from
Edinburgh Custom House to George Chalmers, Smith reiterated his sentiment: ‘You
know that I have little faith in Political Arithmetic’ (Smith, Correspondence,
p. 288). There were serious limitations in gathering and analyzing
quantitative information during the early introduction of vaccination to
England, and no wonder many, like Smith, put little faith in numbers.
Davenant gave a good definition to the term Political
Arithmetick: “By Political Arithmetick, we mean the art of reasoning by
figures, upon things relating to government.” (Hoppit, 1996) The golden age of
political arithmetick began in 1662 with the publication of John Graunt’s book
“Natural and Political Observations upon the Bills of Mortality”, and passing
with the death of its key proponents, Gregory King in 1712 and Charles Davenant
in 1714. The term itself was devised by Sir William Petty in about 1671 or
1672. The use of statistics in policy debate became more prevalent at around
the same period. It is up to one’s imagination to count the areas which were
influenced by Political Arithmetick – social order, military matters, religious
affiliation, economic performance, public finances, to name a few.
Furthermore, ‘Medical Arithmetick’ was being enthusiastically championed by
1780s, though its origins are rooted in much earlier periods. As another
author put it ‘Without medical arithmetic it is impossible to reach the
“grandeur of generality”, the sublime of medical divination.’(Hoppit, 1996).
Almost a century after Adam Smith’s remark about
unreliability of political arithmetick, a medical man, Dr. Guy, was presenting
a paper on smallpox and vaccination at The Royal Statistical Society, and to
the question whether vaccination were a preventive of smallpox, he answered
that “there can be no answer except such as is couched in the language of
figures” (Greenwood, 1930). An amazing contrast in faith in numbers, isn’t
it? Where does it come from? The thing is proponents of vaccination then and
now had no other way of proving the efficacy of vaccines, smallpox vaccine in
particular, than talking in the language of numbers. Even though it may sound
very odd, medicine had little role in proving efficacy of vaccines. The thing
is vaccines are injected mostly to people in near-perfect health, and it would
be very unethical to expose control groups to the dreadful diseases in order to
prove the efficacy of vaccines. The proponents of vaccination, people with
strong ties in the governments and pharmaceutical-medical industry, have been
trying to prove the efficacy of vaccines through statistical study of
population mortality and morbidity, often making unbelievable claims. Having
reviewed dozens of historical materials about smallpox vaccination, I saw an
obvious “play with numbers” in order to reach “politically correct”
conclusions. Medical historians McKeown and Record stated that 'the data (on
mortality and natality) are so treacherous that they can be interpreted to fit
any hypothesis' (Razzell, 1965).
Few tables below will illustrate this point:
Table 2. Mean
Annual Rate of Mortality per million from smallpox at all ages in three groups
of years, selected with reference to optional
and obligatory
vaccination (Milnes, 1897).
Dr.
Ogle’s Division
|
The
Historical Division
|
Period
|
Mortality
|
Period
Difference
|
Mortality
|
Period
|
1) Vaccination optional, 1847-53
|
305
|
82,
or 26.8%
|
117,
or 38.8%
|
305
|
1) Vaccination optional, 1847-53
|
2) Vaccination obligatory, but not efficiently
enforced, 1854-71
|
223
|
109,
or 48.8%
|
39,
or 20.7%
|
188
|
2) Vaccination obligatory, but not efficiently
enforced, 1854-67
|
3) Vaccination obligatory, but more efficiently
enforced, 1872-87
|
114
|
149
|
3) Vaccination obligatory, but more efficiently
enforced, 1868-87
|
Fascinatingly, all
other infectious diseases, without any exception, decreased during this period,
contributing to the falling mortality rates in Britain, a lot of them by larger
percentage than smallpox. Moreover, except smallpox, none of those infectious
diseases were confronted by any inoculations and/or vaccines. The below table
will better illustrate the point:
Table 3. Mortality compared,
Smallpox with Fever Group (Typhus, Typhoid, and Simple and Ill-defined) for the
Two periods, 1838-42 and 1871-75 (Milnes,1897).
Infectious Diseases
|
1838-42
|
1871-75
|
Decrease in %
|
Smallpox
|
576
|
414
|
26.4
|
Fever
|
1053
|
575
|
43.4
|
Table 4. Mortality of
Smallpox and Cholera compared, on Average per million, for the Twelve Years
1838-42 and 1847-53, and the Forty-two years 1854-1895 (Milnes, 1897).
Infectious Diseases
|
1838-42 & 1847-53
|
1854-95
|
Decrease in %
|
Smallpox
|
408
|
126
|
69
|
Cholera
|
320
|
69
|
78
|
Hence, with in
regards to the above two tables, it becomes clear that there is no ground to
attribute decline in smallpox mortality to smallpox vaccination, because if
that were the case, smallpox must have declined by far larger percentage
compared to other infectious diseases. This is not a conclusion, which has
been arrived at recently, on contrary this fact has been suppressed for
political purposes, and has been known from the very beginning.
Late Dr. Gryzanovski noted the strange fascination in
numbers: “Not only the mathematician, and the mystic philosopher, but the
artists, the physicist, the economist, all feel it alike, and even those who
are unable to comprehend the real nature of numbers, have an instinctive
appreciation of their conclusiveness”. Below is a good example how numbers can
be misleading if used improperly. During an agitation in favor of compulsory
vaccination in Germany at the end of 19th century, the learned
Professor Kussmaul went into great details by citing the occurrence of 3330
cases of smallpox in Marseilles in 1828. According to the statistics that was
presented by him to prove the necessity of mass vaccination, 2289 of the 3330
persons had not been vaccinated. Out of these unvaccinated folks 420 or 18.3
per cent died, whereas the mortality among the vaccinated 1041 was only 17 or
1.7 per cent. At first sight, it seems obvious that vaccinated folks were
luckier and through saved lives smallpox vaccination caused an invaluable
amount of economic gain, but that is only if we presume that data is correct
and calculation is without any fault. But now we have Dr. Lorinser’s data on
Marseilles’ population in 1828, and proportion of vaccinated, 133000 and 33000
respectively. And if now we recalculate using the correct denominators, we
come up with a completely different picture. In fact, it is the opposite of
the initial finding that supported efficacy of the smallpox vaccination.
Mortality level among the vaccinated comes up to be 32 per thousand, while
mortality level among the unvaccinated is 23 per thousand. This recalculation
of the data at hand not only disproves the initial claims of the efficacy of
smallpox vaccination, but also shows that it was dangerous. So who is right in
this case? Maybe both men’s conclusions were wrong, but Dr. Lorinser’s
statistical methods seem to make more sense. (Gryzanovski, 1906).
Hence, the role of smallpox vaccination in eradicating
the disease in Britain seems to be exaggerated. The first medical tool in
preventing smallpox disease, inoculation, was pronounced illegal after being
carried out on mass level for more than 120 years. It is interesting to note
that from the date of mandatory smallpox vaccination law in Britain in 1853
till the complete eradication of the disease in 1979, almost the same amount of
time had passed as in the previous case. One thing is different though – this
time, with vaccination, medical men decided to end smallpox vaccination on a
good note… After 1979, smallpox cases were spotted in a few LDCs (less
developed countries) of the world, but the WHO did not re-initiate mass
smallpox vaccination.
Conclusions and Directions for A
Future Research
Without a doubt,
eradication of smallpox disease was one of the greatest achievements of
mankind. It must be emphasized that this was the merit of combined forces of
various factors, such as economic, sanitary, technological, and educational.
Arduous endeavors of certain groups to continue with inoculation long after it
had been banned in 1840 were mentioned (NAVL, 1910), and this leads one to
think that these groups probably had huge economic and/or political interests
at stake. Estimation of economic benefits derived from smallpox immunization,
both inoculation and vaccination, would shed light on the special interests
behind this practice. In case of inoculation that preceded vaccination, it
seems to be a very low-cost (both start-up, and operations) and highly
profitable field: all kinds of amateurs (from farmers to custom-officers)
carried out inoculations throughout towns and villages, with little or no
regulation; overseers of the poor paid for their parish to be inoculated. For
instance, the statement that “many gentlemen paid for inoculation of the children
of the poor in their own neighborhoods” does signal huge economic spending on
inoculation, but does in no way quantify the amount (Razzel, 1965). The above
description of smallpox inoculation resembles the current day Internet
get-rich-instantly recipes, which also boast low-cost, huge potential markets,
and little regulation.
Vaccination
replaced the arsenal of medical profession against the infectious diseases, but
little has changed. Many vaccine batches are found to be contaminated even during
our days, and there is still no sure way to inspect their quality, few vaccine
manufacturers work as a monopoly. Vaccine manufacturers and doctors who carry
out the vaccination practice are legally freed from liability on any consequent
damage caused by vaccines (NVIC.COM).
I was not able
to economically compare the weight of smallpox vaccination compared to other
forces, mainly not due to the lack of data on smallpox mortality or economic
and other developments in Britain between 18th and 20th
centuries, but due to impossibility to measure things with he same units. How
would you compare sanitation, increased knowledge of safe food preparation,
better economic standards of living, higher levels of vaccination, and lower
mortality rates? How much is the worth of one human being’s life? If just one
child died after vaccination, and it turns out he was a potential new Einstein,
how does that change economic calculations of losses due to post-vaccine
mortality? I tried to avoid going deep into analyzing mortality rates alone,
because it would become a simple body count, not economics. However, with
little surprise, I discovered that among all the forces that are believed to
have played role in eradicating smallpox, smallpox vaccination remains to be the
most controversial to the date.
Cited Literature
1. Helleiner,
Karl. “The Vital Revolution Reconsidered”. The Canadian Journal of
Economics and Political Science, Vol. 23, No. 1. February 1957.
2. M. Greenwood.
“The Vaccination Problem”. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society,
Vol.93, No.2. 1930.
3. Scott,
Susan. “The Dynamics of Smallpox Epidemics in Britain, 1550-1800”.
Demography, Vol. 30, No. 3, August 1993.
4. Milnes,
Alfred. “Statistics of Smallpox and Vaccination, with Special Reference to
Age-incidence, Sex-incidence, and Sanitation”. Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society, Vol. 60, No. 3. September, 1897.
5. Gryzanovski,
Ernest. “On Collective Phenomena and the Scientific Value of Statistical
Data”. Publications of the American Economic Association, 3rd
Series, Vol. 7, No. 3. August 1906.
6. Encyclopedia
Britannica online. http://www.britannica.com/
7. Krause, J.
T. “Changes in English Fertility and Mortality, 1781-1850”. The Economic History
Review, Vol. 11, No. 1. (1958).
8. The National
Anti-Vaccination League. (NAVL) “For and Against Vaccination”. London, 1910.
9. National
Vaccine Information Centre. NVIC.COM
10. World
Health Organization: Smallpox Vaccination. WHO.ORG
|